US

Political Economics

Alberto Alesina, a founding member of the IGM economic experts panel, passed away in May 2020 – a sad loss for the whole research community. As the remembrances posted by the IGM directors on our website illustrate, Alberto was a fantastic economist, a wonderful person and a friend to many of the panelists.

To mark the sad occasion, we invited both our US and European panels to express their views on aspects of Alberto’s work. We asked the experts whether they agreed or disagreed with the following statements, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:

(a) Political conflict plays a key role in shaping economic decisions, policies and outcomes.

US panel: (b) The US has a smaller social welfare system than other rich countries in part because it is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity.

European panel: (b) Most European countries have larger social welfare systems than the United States in part because the latter is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity.

Of our 43 US experts, 40 participated in this survey; of our 45 European experts, 39 participated – for a total of 79 expert reactions.

Political conflict and the economy

On the first statement, both panels are unanimous that political conflict plays a key role in shaping economic decisions, policies and outcomes. Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 69% of the US panel strongly agree, and 31% agree; and 56% of the European panel strongly agree, and 44% agree.

Among the short comments that the experts are able to include in their responses, Charles Wyplosz at the Graduate Institute, Geneva, notes: ‘This is what Alberto Alesina taught us.’ Caroline Hoxby at Stanford says: ‘My insightful and powerfully-minded colleague Alberto Alesina is responsible for much of the evidence on this point. Read his masterful work.’ Alberto’s Harvard colleague Pol Antras adds: ‘Thank you very everything you taught us, Alberto. Rest in Peace.’

Aaron Edlin at Berkeley points out that: ‘Where there are decisions to be made, there is politics, and where there is politics, there is conflict.’ And Larry Samuelson at Yale explains: ‘Political actors respond to incentives; conflicting incentives play a key role in shaping economic policy and activity.’

A couple of wrinkles come from Franklin Allen at Imperial, who comments: ‘In most countries, this is the case, in my view. In some totalitarian countries, it is not the case though’; while Peter Neary at Oxford states: ‘Hardly controversial in itself. More so is its importance relative to ideology, history, and deep economic forces.’

Anil Kashyap at Chicago provides a link to Alberto’s paper on macroeconomics and politics; while Pete Klenow at Stanford references Alberto’s paper with European panelist Eliana La Ferrara on the positive and negative effects of ethnic diversity on economic policies and outcomes.

Ethnic heterogeneity and support for social welfare systems

The second statement was framed slightly differently in the way it was put to the two panels, but the central idea was the same: whether the fact that the United States is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity than most European countries is the reason for its smaller social welfare system.

On this issue, views are more varied: of the US panel (weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 17% strongly agree, 69% agree, 13% are uncertain, and 1% disagree. The European panel agrees considerably less (though still a majority), expresses more uncertainty (a third), and features more disagreement: 15% strongly agree, 40% agree, 33% are uncertain, and 13% disagree.

Among panelists who agree, Eric Maskin at Harvard says: ‘Alberto Alesina’s writings establish both points quite persuasively’; while Pol Antras comments: ‘I think Alberto convinced most of us that this is part of the reason. Of course, there are many other reasons why.’

Several other panelists mention some of those other reasons, Peter Neary, himself sadly no longer with us, adds: ‘The sad passing of Alberto Alesina reminds us of his work showing this; though ideology and public perceptions of heterogeneity also matter.’ Larry Samuelson comments: ‘The evidence is that people are more supportive of programs whose benefits go to “people like me”.’ Christopher Udry at Northwestern states: ‘But put it differently. It’s not diversity itself. It’s racism.’

A historical perspective comes from Daron Acemoglu at MIT, who says: ‘But unclear how much of this is because of the current effect of these variables or the historical, long-lasting compromises they induced.’ And Angus Deaton at Princeton notes: ‘I think it is less to do with heterogeneity, than with the legacy of slavery and white versus black.’

Among panelists who are say they are uncertain or disagree, Markus Brunnermeier at Princeton notes: ‘Empirical evidence points to it, but Canada might be a counterexample.’ Richard Blundell at University College London asks: ‘Isn’t it more about the underlying inequalities by race and ethnicity in the US rather than race and ethnicity itself?’ And Aaron Edlin concludes: ‘Looking across states with casual empiricism, many of the more diverse appear to have stronger social welfare programs. This gives me pause.’

Pete Klenow and Christian Leuz at Chicago both mention Alberto’s paper with Edward Glaeser and Bruce Sacerdote asking the question: why doesn’t the United States have a European-style welfare state? And Christian directs us to further papers by Alberto and colleagues on immigration and preferences for redistribution.

All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results.

Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh

Question A:

Political conflict plays a key role in shaping economic decisions, policies and outcomes.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question B:

The US has a smaller social welfare system than other rich countries in part because it is more heterogeneous by race and ethnicity.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Question A Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Strongly Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Sorry, is this a question posed by a visitor from a foreign planet?
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago
Strongly Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Strongly Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Strongly Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Strongly Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Strongly Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Strongly Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
I've seen it happen many times, with both positive and negative social effects.
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Where there are decisions to be made, there is politics, and where there is politics there is conflict.
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Strongly Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Strongly Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
The Narrow Corridor makes a compelling case for this proposition
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
My insightful and powerfully-minded colleague Alberto Alesina is responsible for much of the evidence on this point.Read his masterful work.
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Strongly Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Strongly Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Strongly Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Political actors respond to incentives; conflicting incentives play a key role in shaping economic policy and activity.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Strongly Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Strongly Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History

Question B Participant Responses

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
But unclear how much of this is because of the current effect of these variables or the historical, long-lasting compromises they induced.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Uncertain
7
Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Uncertain
7
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Empirical evidence points to it, but Canada might be a counterexample.
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Strongly Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Alberto Alesina taught us about this. I miss him already.
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Strongly Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
I think it is less to do with heterogeneity, than with the legacy of slavery and white v black.
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Uncertain
2
Bio/Vote History
I'm not expert enough to handle this question.
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Disagree
2
Bio/Vote History
Looking across states with casual empiricism, many of the more diverse appear to have stronger social welfare programs. This gives me pause.
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Strongly Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Depressing thought of the day
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
That is what some experts have made a case for
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Plays probably some role, but I don't know that one can identify it's significance. So many other factors.
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
Economics has lost one of its greatest thinkers with our losing Alberto Alesina.
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
I would add income and cultural heterogeneity.
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
7
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Alberto Alesina's writings establish both points quite persuasively.
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
The evidence is that people are more supported of programs whose benefits go to "people like me".
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
The question states "in part". Another question is "how big a part"?
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Strongly Agree
10
Bio/Vote History
But put it differently. It's not diversity itself. It's racism.