US

Energy Sanctions

As Russia’s invasion of Ukraine continues and many call for a strengthening of sanctions, an alternative to a full energy embargo has been discussed in the form of European Union tariffs on imports of Russian gas. We invited our European and US experts to express their views on this proposal, asking both panels whether they agree or disagree with the following statement, and, if so, how strongly and with what degree of confidence:

High tariffs imposed by the European Union on imports of Russian natural gas would be an effective measure to reduce the flow of revenues to Russia while limiting disruption to supplies to Europe.

Of our 43 US experts, 41 participated in this survey; of our 47 European experts, 36 participated – for a total of 77 expert reactions. Nearly three-quarters of the panelists agree or strongly agree with the statement (among whom European experts were more likely to say they strongly agree), most of the rest are uncertain, and a handful disagrees.

Weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response, 27% of the European panel strongly agree, 48% agree, 22% are uncertain, and 3% disagree. Among the US panel (again weighted by each expert’s confidence in their response), 6% strongly agree, 67% agree, 18% are uncertain, and 9% disagree. Overall, across both panels, 16% strongly agree, 57% agree, 20% are uncertain, and 6% disagree (totals don’t always sum to 100 because of rounding).

More details on the experts’ views come in the short comments that they are able to include when they participate in the survey. Among those who agree or strongly agree, Franklin Allen at Imperial College London says: ‘This would reduce the money going to Russia, lessen the damage for European economies and potentially provide funds for rebuilding Ukraine.’ William Nordhaus at Yale adds: ‘High and rising tariffs are clearly the best approach, mainly to avoid quantitative restrictions.’ And Christopher Udry at Northwestern directs us to a recent VoxEU piece on ‘the simple economics of a tariff on Russian energy imports’.

Among the panelists who say that they are uncertain, Beata Javorcik at Oxford comments:
‘Russia is likely to retaliate and cut off gas supplies to Europe.’ Austan Goolsbee at Chicago notes: ‘It would hurt them but would also hurt Europe.’ And Lubos Pastor at Chicago argues: ‘This would hurt EU countries unevenly. Within-EU solidarity would be necessary. Gas is hard to substitute in the short run.’

All of the experts who disagree with the statement add short explanatory comments for their opinions. They include Pinelopi Goldberg at Yale who states: ‘Sanctions have never worked. And in the present context, the EU would be paying a high price.’ Richard Schmalensee at MIT protests: ‘WTO-illegal, may violate contracts, Russian response uncertain. EU economists seem to favor disruption-contingent price caps.’ And Bengt Holmstrom at MIT concludes: ‘If effective means bringing the war to an end, tariffs won’t do it.’

Elasticities and price-setting mechanisms

Several panelists suggest the significance of the elasticities of demand for and supply of Russian gas, as well as the mechanisms by which prices are set. Among those who agree, David Autor at MIT remarks: ‘High substitutability of non-Russian and Russian gas means that Russia should bear most of the incidence.’ Olivier Blanchard at the Peterson Institute mentions: ‘Russia might decide to sell elsewhere, but at a lower price (Ural discount). May not decrease world supply much.’ And Patrick Honohan at Trinity College Dublin warns: ‘But the effectiveness depends on elasticities of substitution in the importing countries, on which there is a wide range of opinion.’

Others who agree are similarly cautious. Larry Samuelson at Yale observes: ‘There is a tradeoff – higher tariffs would be more effective in limiting revenue, but would also pose more disruption.’ And Pol Antras at Harvard declares: ‘Given likely tariff incidence, it sounds like a good policy. But I am less sure supply won’t be disrupted. In any case, a risk worth taking.’ He directs us to a piece written shortly after the invasion on the case for punitive taxes on Russian energy.

Panelists who say they are uncertain also mention elasticities and likely incidence. Karl Whelan at University College Dublin replies: ‘Unclear where the short-run incidence of this tariff lies. With difficulties in sourcing alternative supplies, it may just raise EU prices.’ Anil Kashyap at Chicago states: ‘Hard to know about the demand elasticity and speed at which adjustments can be made.’ Daniel Sturm at the London School of Economics adds: ‘It is unclear whether the tariffs would lead to substantial declines in Russian export prices over a relevant time horizon.’ And Christian Leuz at Chicago concludes: ‘Could send very important political and symbolic message. But economic effect hard to predict; depends on demand and supply elasticities and pricing mechanisms.’

Opinions on likely elasticities are also expressed by experts who disagree with the statement. Jan Pieter Krahnen at Goethe University Frankfurt states: ‘This is a question of tariff incidence; demand for gas is currently price inelastic, revenues for the exporter may thus not fall at all.’ And Michael Greenstone at Chicago suggests that: ‘Near term, tariffs would do little: there aren’t substitutes. Longer-term phase-in would work better.’

Full embargo

Finally, two of the experts who agree allude to the alternative sanction to energy tariffs of a full embargo. Daron Acemoglu at MIT says: ‘“Effective” yes, but probably not as effective as complete bans. The exact effect on Europe is also hard to know.’ And Pete Klenow at Stanford links to a widely discussed report on the potential economic effects on Germany of a stop on all energy imports from Russia.

All comments made by the experts are in the full survey results for the US and European panels.

Romesh Vaitilingam
@econromesh
May 2022

High tariffs imposed by the European Union on imports of Russian natural gas would be an effective measure to reduce the flow of revenues to Russia while limiting disruption to supplies to Europe.

Responses weighted by each expert's confidence

Participant University Vote Confidence Bio/Vote History
Acemoglu
Daron Acemoglu
MIT
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
"Effective" yes, but probably not as effective as complete bans. The exact effect on Europe is also hard to know.
Altonji
Joseph Altonji
Yale
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Auerbach
Alan Auerbach
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Autor
David Autor
MIT
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
High substitutability of non-Russian and Russian gas means that Russia should bear most of the incidence
Baicker
Katherine Baicker
University of Chicago
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Banerjee
Abhijit Banerjee
MIT
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Bertrand
Marianne Bertrand
Chicago
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Brunnermeier
Markus Brunnermeier
Princeton
Strongly Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Chetty
Raj Chetty
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Chevalier
Judith Chevalier
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Cutler
David Cutler
Harvard
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Deaton
Angus Deaton
Princeton
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Duffie
Darrell Duffie
Stanford
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Edlin
Aaron Edlin
Berkeley
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Eichengreen
Barry Eichengreen
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Einav
Liran Einav
Stanford
Agree
1
Bio/Vote History
Fair
Ray Fair
Yale
Uncertain
5
Bio/Vote History
Finkelstein
Amy Finkelstein
MIT
Agree
2
Bio/Vote History
Goldberg
Pinelopi Goldberg
Yale
Disagree
5
Bio/Vote History
Sanctions have never worked. And in the present context, the EU would be paying a high price.
Goolsbee
Austan Goolsbee
Chicago
Uncertain
4
Bio/Vote History
It would hurt them but would also hurt europe.
Greenstone
Michael Greenstone
University of Chicago
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
near term, tariffs would do little. there aren't substitutes longer term phase in would work better
Hall
Robert Hall
Stanford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
A tariff lowers the net-of-tariff price to the seller and lowers quantity demanded by the buyer.
Hart
Oliver Hart
Harvard
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Holmström
Bengt Holmström
MIT
Disagree
6
Bio/Vote History
If effective means bringing the war to an end, tariffs won’t do it.
Hoxby
Caroline Hoxby
Stanford
Agree
9
Bio/Vote History
Hoynes
Hilary Hoynes
Berkeley
Uncertain
6
Bio/Vote History
Judd
Kenneth Judd
Stanford
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Kaplan
Steven Kaplan
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Kashyap
Anil Kashyap
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
3
Bio/Vote History
Hard to know about the demand elasticity and speed at which adjustments can be made.
Klenow
Pete Klenow
Stanford
Agree
4
Bio/Vote History
Levin
Jonathan Levin
Stanford
Agree
3
Bio/Vote History
Maskin
Eric Maskin
Harvard Did Not Answer Bio/Vote History
Nordhaus
William Nordhaus
Yale
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
High and rising tariffs are clearly the best approach, mainly to avoid quantitative restrictions.
Obstfeld
Maurice Obstfeld
Berkeley
Agree
5
Bio/Vote History
Saez
Emmanuel Saez
Berkeley
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
Samuelson
Larry Samuelson
Yale
Agree
6
Bio/Vote History
There is a tradeoff - higher tariffs would be more effective in limiting revenue, but would also pose more disruption.
Scheinkman
José Scheinkman
Columbia University
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Schmalensee
Richard Schmalensee
MIT
Disagree
4
Bio/Vote History
WTO-illegal, may violate contracts, Russian response uncertain. EU economists seem to favor disruption-contingent price caps.
Shapiro
Carl Shapiro
Berkeley
Uncertain
7
Bio/Vote History
Shimer
Robert Shimer
University of Chicago
Agree
8
Bio/Vote History
Stock
James Stock
Harvard
Agree
7
Bio/Vote History
Thaler
Richard Thaler
Chicago Booth
Uncertain
1
Bio/Vote History
Udry
Christopher Udry
Northwestern
Strongly Agree
4
Bio/Vote History